The Scope of Public Choice Theory

The Scope of Public Choice Theory

Tibor R. Machan

Prague, Czech Republic. In October 1985 (I think it was) Professor James
Buchanan, now at George Mason University’s Department of Economics,
received the Nobel Prize in his discipline for his pioneering work—in
collaboration with Professor Gordon Tullock—in what came to be called
public choice theory. The gist of this theory is that those who work in
government, often referred to in the honorific terms as doing "public
service," are, contrary to widespread impression, just as much motivated
by personal or self-interest as are people in the market place. In other
words, politicians and bureaucrats pursue their own agendas, not those of
"the public," just as people in business do. And from this a number of
interesting insights follow about the nature of government policy.

What makes this idea quite credible even at first inspection is that
politicians and bureaucrats would have a very hard time, even if they
wanted to, to serve the public interest. The reason is that the public is
a huge group of individuals with a great variety of different interests
and just a few common ones. All those people in centers of power who
lobby for support from various branches and divisions of government—those
folks so scornfully dismissed as looking out for mere "special
interests"—are, in fact, the only ones who can provide politicians and
bureaucrats with some clue as to what the public’s interest amounts to.
They tell them, actually, about a lot of highly diverse private and
special interests, not any kind of public interest at all.

This fact is very important to keep in mind, especially in the midst of
political campaigns during which there is an inordinate amount of rhetoric
about the special interests versus the public interest, the goals of
different people versus the will of the people. Of course, the special
interest groups are nothing other than the people, so the will of the
people is really nothing else but the sum of the special interests all
those nasty lobbyists are promoting.

Even beyond all this, public choice theory also alerts us to the fact that
the most recent effort to shore up the case for government meddling in our
lives, namely so called libertarian paternalism—or nudging—is infested
with the problem that behavior that may be desirable from certain citizens
will not be so from others. What the politicians and bureaucrats choose to
nudge us to do—which is really a form of insidious manipulation even at
its best—is rarely what all of us being so nudged really ought to do. The
assumption of one-size-fits-all is blatant and public policies that follow
from it must of necessity misfire.

Suppose there is a problem in a society, say, environmental pollution.
What everyone ought to do about it is quite impossible to say. One
person or family may have to address it one way, another very differently,
and so on down the line. To believe, for example, that everyone who owns
an SUV ought to get rid of it because of pollution is the height of
ignorance and presumption. What one person or one family or one company
ought to do to address the problem will be quite different from what
another ought to, in light of the different circumstances and needs and
possibilities of all these different human agents.

Because this is so, the effort to address the problem by politicians and
bureaucrats is invariably going to misfire. Those so called public
servants, in short, have no clue at all what needs to be done by you, me,
our friends, colleagues, neighbors, and the rest, so they will promote
policies they happen to prefer, never mind whether they help solve the
problem. They will, as customary, feel the urge to "do something," even
if there is no demonstrable connection between it and any solution to the
problem that is supposedly being addressed.

The same goes for those doing the nudging being promoted these days as
ways to get us to behave properly. Right conduct is highly contextual. It
depends on highly particular conditions that people face. Only those close
to us have a decent chance of knowing the best way for us to act, so
public servants will necessarily be off base.

Sadly in their eagerness to impose their so called solutions, politicians
and bureaucrats are not likely to relinquish their power over us, never
mind how misguided they are in doing so.

This entry was posted in Uncategorized. Bookmark the permalink.

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out / Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out / Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out / Change )

Google+ photo

You are commenting using your Google+ account. Log Out / Change )

Connecting to %s